Final Results

RNS Number : 6867E
Caledonian Trust PLC
24 December 2009
 




Caledonian Trust PLC

24 December 2009



Caledonian Trust PLC


Results for the year ended 30 June 2009


Caledonian Trust PLC, the Edinburgh-based property investment holding and development company, announces its audited results for the year to 30 June 2009.


CHAIRMAN'S STATEMENT 

 

YEAR ENDED 30 JUNE 2009

 

Introduction

The Group made a pre-tax profit £1,346,000 in the year to 30 June 2009 compared with a loss of £7,875,000 last year.  Excluding investment property revaluations the Group made a trading loss of £71,000 compared with £714,000 last year. The profit per share was 11.33p and the NAV per share was 167.8p compared with 156.6p last year. 


Income from rent, service charges and dilapidations was £731,000 compared with £842,000 last year. Rental income fell £143,000 due to the sale of investment property and the determination of leases in Young Street and 57 North Castle. Gains from the sales of properties were £560,000 compared with £105,000 last year. Other operating income was £254,000 after including the final settlement of £222,000 at St Magnus Aberdeen compared with £61,000 last year. 


Net interest payable was £457,000£177,000 less than last year due to lower borrowings and lower interest rates.  The weighted average base rate for the year was 2.49% compared with 5.45 %. 


Review of Activities


The Group's property activities have continued to be concentrated on enhancing the value of our development properties principally by working towards or gaining more valuable planning consents.


The Group's Edinburgh New Town investment portfolio has changed further this year. In 17 Young Street, adjacent to Charlotte Square, the tenants exercised their option to determine the lease in August 2008. We agreed a dilapidation payment and after marketing the property for office or residential use it was sold in July 2009 for £407,500, above the then valuation. We obtained planning and listed building consent to return the vacant Georgian ground and first floors of 61 North Castle Street to residential use and to incorporate the Edwardian extension to the rear of 61 North Castle Street into the existing office space in Hill Street. The Georgian property was sold in May 2009 for £475,000 and the balance of the property was valued at £625,000 in June 2009 giving a total value of £1.1m compared with £975,000 at June 2008.  


57 North Castle Street, the adjacent building, was vacated by the City of Edinburgh Council in March 2008 and was subject to dilapidations claim which was eventually settled by an Expert determination with costs against the tenants. Subsequently planning and listed building consent was granted to divide the property into two residential units, a ground and first floor townhouse and a basement flat. The town house was sold in September 2009 for £540,000 which, together with the current basement valuation of £275,000, is considerably above the June 2008 valuation of £675,000. Work has started on the reconversion of the basement into a two bedroom flat for sale in the Spring.


The Group's other New Town property, 9 South Charlotte Street, between Charlotte Square and Princes Street, is let to La Tasca for a further 17 years. In the improving investment market the lease length and the quality of the covenant make this an attractive investment. Early in 2009 we sold our last investment property in Aberdeen, a warehouse/office unit at Wellheads RoadDyce, adjacent to the BP HQ, to the tenants for £50,000 over the recent revaluation. 


St Margaret's House, London Road, is our largest property in Edinburgh, where we are pursuing different short and long-term objectives. The building is wholly let on peppercorn short-term lets to charitable causes. In April we let almost all the car parking spaces to our neighbours, the Registrars of Scotland, on a short-term lease. We have made considerable progress towards our long-term objective for a large-scale redevelopment. In June 2007 our Architects produced an "Urban Analysis Report" and in July 2007 Draft Development Proposals from which the City of Edinburgh Council suggested that a Development Brief be prepared covering St Margaret'sthe adjacent 125,000ftMeadowbank House, owned and occupied by the Registrars of Scotland, and all the smaller varied properties lying between the A1 and "Smokey Brae". The preparation of this "Brief" involved considerable time and preparation including six community consultations over three months! The Development Brief was adopted by the City of Edinburgh Council in August 2009, so providing a "Master Plan" for the whole area. In July 2009 we lodged an application for outline consent for a 225,000ft2 mixed use development of residential and/or student accommodationan hotel and commercial space. This proposal is now the subject of detailed discussion between the Council and our Architects, and should be finalised next year


Considerable progress has been made in our large development sites at Waterloo, London SE1. Last year we attempted to negotiate with Lambeth Council to purchase the contiguous garage site owned by them or to enter into an agreement with them to our mutual benefit by realising the considerable marriage value. Agreement has not been reached but the opportunity remains. Ware promoting smaller schemes within our own site. One scheme provides 140 rooms for student accommodation together with 1,152ft2 retail accommodation in the ground floor on our site only, but is capable of extension into the garage site. There are 250,000 full time students in London where student rents increased by 10% in 2008/09 and numbers and rents are expected to continue to rise.


In Glasgow, on the south side of the Clyde opposite the Broomielaw, now connected by an attractive modern pedestrian bridge, we own 100 West Street, Tradeston, currently a bespoke car showroom let to the Eastern Western Group. The May 2006 review was settled this year at £213,000, an uplift of 21.8%. Tradeston and the surrounding district is benefiting from an extensive improvement programme, including the demolition or conversion of several Victorian industrial warehouses and the development of the pedestrian bridge and its landscaped boulevard. As well as amenity improvements, vehicular access will be greatly improved when the extension of the M74 through Tradeston to meet the existing nearby M8 at the Kingston Bridge is completed in 2011, the date of the next review. That review is subject to a minimum uplift of 16% without any consideration for the prospective improvement in the location. The current valuation is based on the passing rent and the high investment yields extant in June and places no value on our existing consent for a development of 191 flats, predominantly two and three bedrooms, together with dedicated parking and 10,000ft2 of commercial space.


In Tradeston we also own a small secondary shopping parade at 1-7 Scotland Street purchased in January 2005 in the expectation that the area would improve as the changes outlined in Tradeston above were realised. Once the M74 is completed, the disruption ended and access is improved the area will become "less secondary" and the rents reversionary. 


We have three development sites in or near Edinburgh on which we decided in 2007 to delay development because of the worsening economic conditions. In Belford Road, Edinburgh, a quiet cul-de-sac, less than 500m from Charlotte Square and the West End of Princes Street we have a long-standing office consent for 22,500ft2 and 14 cars which has been technically "commenced". We also have a separate residential consent for 20,000ft2 and 20 cars. Even in the present depressed residential market a residential development is more valuable than an office development, as prices of £350 to £450/ft2 were achieved in the area during the particularly depressed first half of 2009. We will seek to improve the existing residential consent and to redesign the structure to simplify construction and to increase the space. In August 2006, five years after the original application, consent was granted for eight detached houses at Wallyford which borders Musselburgh and is within 400 yards of the East Coast mainline station near the A1/A720 City Bypass junction, contiguous to a development of 250 houses by two national house builders which is over 90% complete. In Wallyford we consider that the market for smaller houses has improved relative to larger houses and we have lodged an application to replace the two largest detached houses with a terrace of four, providing ten houses altogether with a larger saleable area. In East Edinburgh at Brunstane Farm, adjacent to Brunstane rail station, we hold a consent to reconstruct an existing cottage attached to the farm steading and to convert the steading into nine houses of various sizes totalling 14,000ft2 altogether. Beyond this steading lies another detached stone building on which consent was granted in May 2009 for conversion to a detached house extending to 3,500ft2 on open ground with views to the Forth estuary. We expect to install French windows in the existing five two-storey stone farm cottages to improve their southern aspect.  


Brunstane is in the Green Belt from which we made three separate unsuccessful applications for abstraction. However, once the redevelopment is complete and a large area to the South recently abstracted from the Green Belt is developed, a reassessment of the existing Green Belt boundaries, including two-and-a-half acres of scrubland which we own contiguous with Brunstane steading, is possible. Any abstraction from the Green Belt would be very valuable.


The Company owns 15 separate rural development opportunities, 9 in Perthshire, 3 in Fife, 2 in Argyll & Bute and 1 in East Dunbartonshire, almost all in accessible locations set in areas of high amenity. Unsurprisingly, proposals for any change there meet local opposition, usually vocal and often well co-ordinated. The new requirement to be outside the 1 in 200 year flood plan (i.e. 0.05% chance of flooding) can eliminate sites that pass all other tests. Small sites are by definition less financially rewarding to local authorities and less important in achieving their housing targets and support and priority in treatment from planning authorities is often "patchy". The elected members of the planning committees now gain their seats on the council by proportional representation and are much more influenced by individual constituents' concerns than previously. Thus the process of gaining planning consent for small well-located developments has become much more tortuous and in some cases the scale of development had been restricted beyond what in many cases originally seemed appropriate and reasonable. Paradoxically, the more tortuous the process becomes, the more restricted the permissions are, the more the overall supply is restricted, and the more valuable the reduced consents become. 


In spite of all these difficulties I am pleased to report that considerable success has now been achieved in our planning applications. At Ardonachie Farm steading, near Perth, after extensive and detailed discussion with the planning authority, we submitted a planning application for sixteen houses over 20,000ft2. However, due to policy changes, we resubmitted an application for ten houses over 16,429ft2, including a new "farmhouse", in June 2008 which was approved in February 2009. At Tomperran, a smallholding set in Comrie, where we submitted an application for twelve houses over 19,047ft2 iNovember 2007, we were required to change the proposed layout again, having previously adjusted it to accommodate a cycle path requested by the Council, which was approved in July 2009. The smallholding includes two acres zoned for industrial use and about 34 acres adjacent to the settlement, a proportion of which will be promoted for a housing allocation in the now long-overdue Strathearn Local Plan. At Chance Inn, where we had previously applied for seventeen houses plus four affordable houses, in April 2009 we applied for a revised scheme containing ten private houses over 21,836ftwhich was approved in September 2009. At Balnaguard, where originally we applied for nine houses over 15,719ft2we reapplied for a different configuration of 16,254ft2 which was approved in July 2009. At Myreside Farm, in the Carse of Gowrie between Perth and Dundee, we await the decision on the application lodged in September 2007 for eight houses totalling 12,410ft2 on the steading adjacent to the attractive listed farmhouse.  Planning permission is being sought at two other sites in Perthshire. At Strathtay we have submitted alternative proposals for four and three large detached houses within the village envelope and both proposals are presently at appeal. At Carnbo we have submitted a proposal for four houses, revised from the original six houses, in the large garden of the former farmhouse. 


Planning considerations will also be pivotal in the development of our two properties at Gartshore near Kirkintilloch and at Ardpatrick on West Loch Tarbert, Argyll. Gartshore, derived from Old Scots "garden" and (loch) shore forms the heart of a large estate, formerly owned by the Baird family, the then largest Coal and Iron Masters in Scotland, before passing to the Whitelaw family, now extends to about 200 acres (77ha) of which about 80 acres comprises policies, designed landscape and gardens including a magnificent Georgian stone pigeonnier and a huge walled garden. The main remaining building is a 15,000ft2 Victorian stable block, the large mansion house built in 1885 having been demolished in 1950sGartshore is only seven miles from central Glasgow, two miles from the M73/M80 junction and three miles from two Glasgow/Edinburgh mainline stations (Croy and Lenzie) and Cumbernauld commuter station. In our publication "A Secret to Share" we are promoting Gartshore, a site in the very centre of Scotland with excellent communications, as having enclosed landscaped sites within a designed landscape with mature trees suitable for high-quality offices together with destination leisure centre, created from the restoration of the paths, avenues, walled gardens, and built landscape features. As this specification is unique in East Dunbartonshire we hope to promote Gartshore in conjunction with the Local Authority. Gartshore offers an immediately available site in a mature setting requiring no remediation and not suffering any of the sometimes difficult and long-delayed procedures associated with brownfield sitesThe restoration of the designed landscape could include a scattering of "executive" detached housing to offer a unique "Garden Park" 


At Ardpatrick, West Loch Tarbert, Argyll consents have been granted to divide the house in four, to build one new house, to convert the stone garden shed to a house, to make the existing coach house and flat into two dwellings and to undertake certain residential extensions. These are conditional on certain upgrading works to the UC33 Ardpatrick Ferry Road.


The main development opportunity at Ardpatrick lies in the development of "new" houses in areas designated as "Rural Development Opportunities" in the Local Plan. The Reporter at the Local Plan Inquiry recommended that the areas designated as "Rural Development Opportunities" should be reviewed by suitably-qualified landscape architects, especially those in areas of greatest landscape sensitivity.  The result of the survey at South Knapdale which includes Ardpatrick is expected to be published shortly. Although much of the Ardpatrick landscape is of exceptional quality most of our proposals relate to areas where intrusion is minimal and we expect to be able to undertake appropriate developments in such areas. 


Wcontinue the long process of enhancing the values of our properties at Ardpatrick damaged by years of neglectwhich has resulted in buildings becoming ruinous, houses falling into disrepair, ditches and drains becoming blocked, roadways becoming impassable and walls, gates and fences becoming broken or unserviceable, all impairing amenity and restricting residential and agricultural use. Much of the Estate's residential property has now been restored, including two houses within the house curtilage. Three outlying cottages were repaired and sold in 2007 and a fourth, the Old Post Office, at the northern extreme of the Estate was extensively restored and sold earlier this year for £162,000. In the autumn of 2008 these outlying buildings whose structural integrity had been compromised were secured and currently two large detached houses, Honey House and Stables House are undergoing building work to safeguard them prior to major repairs. At Ardpatrick House the rainwater goodhave been extensively overhauled and repaired, essential repairs have been done on the roof and extensive structural repairs have been completed. In the drier summer months good progress was made repairing walls, ditches, roads and fences and controlling weeds, all of which enhances the agricultural and amenity value of the Estate. The foundations of the Estate's restoration have been laid and the effect of future work will be much more apparent.


Last year we judged that the agricultural arable land values had risen to levels higher than the prospective returns for agriculture justified and we decided to sell the lands at Larennie in Fife and at Chance Inn, near Kinross, while retaining the residential buildings, steadings and appropriate inbye or prospective development land. This land was under offer last year and subsequently sold at very attractive prices. As the land at Ardpatrick is not arable and has a high marriage value with the Estate, it is being retained and improved. 


Economic Prospects

The UK has completed its sixth quarter of economic contraction, falling a revised 0.3% in the three months to September 2009, resulting in a total contraction of 6.1% points including a swingeing fall of 2.4% in Q1 2009. This is proving the UK's longest and deepest post-war recession, surpassing the 4.7% contraction of the early 1980s recession. The economic contraction may even exceed that of the 1930s where, on different basis, a 5.4% fall was recorded. 


The 1930s recession was marked by very high unemployment, 3.4m or 16.5% of the workforce at its peak, but in the 1980s, although unemployment was almost as high at 3.3m, it represented 11.9% of the workforce, a much lower incidence. Currently "only" 2.47m are unemployed, or 7.9% of the workforce, a much lower percentage, but the recession is not yet over and unemployment is usually a lagging indicator. The UK's deepening recession contrasts with the re-expansion of all other major economies


The UK recession, although it arrived unexpectedly and abruptly, was adumbrated by the vivid image of depositors queuing round the block at Northern Rock in late 2007, thfirst run on any UK bank since the Bank of Glasgow collapsed in 1878. When Northern Rock collapsed the Governor wrote an incisive essay on the evils of moral hazard before fortunately, but after much valuable time had been lost, the MPC loosened monetary policy. Growth continued in the first quarter of 2008 at a high annualised rate of 3.2% and the consensus forecast then was for continuing growth, but falling to 2% in 2009. As late as August 2008 the Bank identified escalating inflation as the key risk and economic output was then projected to be "flat", but in that quarter, when interest rates were still 5%, the UK entered recession with an economic contraction of 0.7% following one of 0.1%. By November 2008 the Bank's greater concern was deflation and it then forecast a peak-to-trough decline in GDP of about 1.9% with the recession lasting into late 2009. The Governor reversed his previously stated opposition to a fiscal stimulus, saying the "transmission mechanism" of monetary policy had become impaired through the banking crisis. In accordance with this change the Bank cut interest rates to 3% in November 2008, and stressed that fiscal policy was likely to be relaxed and that the MPC would be able to take further action to lower interest rates in the months to come, a commitment delivered by the cut to 2% in December, equal to the lowest level since 1694. By way of some reassurance the Governor said that the expected recession would not be like Japan's "lost decade", of 1996 to 2005, but milder like Sweden's in the early 1990s: a recession that lasted from 1990 to 1993 with a contraction of almost 5%. At least he did not compare it to the great US depression. Cuts of 0.50% point in the repo rate followed in the next three months coinciding with the 2.4% contraction in activity in the first quarter of 2009. The UK was not alone in this sudden adjustment as the whole world fell into a deep recession. Annualised moving average world industrial output fell an estimated 25% and world trade even more.


Recessions are a recurring feature of market economies. In the UK they have occurred in every decade since WWI and in the US 15 times since 1926. There is no common cause for these recessions but recurring themes have been wars, external shocks, particularly oil prices and defaults, inflation, and asset booms in finance and property. The current recession is clearly not as a result of the aftermath of conflict nor of an external shock or inflation: the underlying cause is the collapse of an asset boom, or bubble.


Two categories of asset bubble can be differentiated, called for convenience "pure irrational exuberance bubble" and "credit boom bubble". The bursting of both types of bubbles can cause recessions but the "irrational" bubble is benign compared to the malign "credit" bubble. Benign bubbles do not involve credit, or the "cycle of leveraging against higher asset values", as Professor Frederic Mishkin, a former governor of the Fed describes. The "irrational" bubble in the high tech stocks which burst dramatically in the late 1990s did not cause much collateral damage and was not accompanied by a marked deterioration in bank balance sheets. Similarly the stock market bubble in the late 1980s was not primarily sustained by credit and so, when it burst in 1987, did not put the financial system under great stress, so allowing the economy to recover quickly.


Unfortunately, malign or credit bubbles are much more dangerous. The Great US Depression that lasted almost four years from 1929 in which employment fell 30% was preceded by a bubble in stock market prices fuelled by a credit boom, represented by margin purchases of stocks and a boom in the relatively new instalment credit, and a fall in savingsThe similarities of the present credit based consumption bubble burst are very high. The evolution of such an economic cycle was described by Hyman P Minsky in 1992 as a Financial Instability Hypothesis. Minsky portrayed three types of borrower: a hedge borrower repaying interest and principal; a speculative borrower repaying interest; and a ponzi borrower repaying out of capital appreciation, a series of overlapping but progressive stages which characterised the credit and housing bubbles up to August 2007.


The instability described in the "Minsky" cycle results primarily from the asset based inflation and the ponzi lending based on such inflation being mutually reinforcing which he describes: "capitalist economies exhibit inflations and debt deflations which seem to have the potential to spin out of control ….. the economic system's reaction to a movement of the economy amplify the movement - inflation fuels an inflation and debt deflation fuels a debt deflation". In investment terms such speculation might be described as momentum rather than value investing, a strategy that expands the apex and nadir of cycles. The "ponzi" lending contributing to this Minsky cycle was facilitated by the emergence of purchasers for the securitised assets, SIVS, conduits, CDOs etc of financial engineering, a product of financial deregulation, which in turn was dependent on the new lending opportunity afforded by sub-prime borrowers. Securitisation, broadly deployed into consumer markets where it extended beyond housing to credit cards and auto credit was a major financial innovation and may have been the catalyst allowing all the other ingredients determining this particular Minsky cycle to coalesce. Certainly many other cases have followed a financial innovation such as securitisation or a technical innovation, a process described in "Manias, Panics, and Crashes" by Kindleberger as "displacements" of normal investors' expectations: the concept of a joint stock company was followed by the South Sea Bubble and the Mississippi Bubble of 1720; the development of new electrical and transport technologies in the 1920s, resulting in then hi-tech stocks like RCA rising 1000% to a PE of 73 stimulating "ponzi" speculation, often on a margin, preceded the 1929 crash and the Great Depression; the internet technologies developing in the 1990s produced the "irrational exuberance" that preceded the dot.com crash in 2001.


Minsky cycles, such as we have just experienced, are predominantly associated with developing countries, but now one has occurred in the very heart of the world economy, in countries accounting for about half the world economy with the USA and the UK particularly affected. Paul Volcker put it: "Simply stated, the bright new financial system - for all its talented participants, for all its rich rewards - failed the test of the market place". The economic crisis resulting form this Minsky cycle is the worst since the 1930s. The overriding threat to the economy was of systemic risk i.e. the collapse of the banking system and in its wake the whole financial system and, indeed, the present structure of society. The risk was recognised as immediate and the costs calamitous and all affected administrations set aside all moral, political, administrative and ideological considerations in the rescue.


Fortunately the rescue has worked, or, as the Economist put it "deft policy saw off calamity". How very near that calamity was has only recently been revealed - now too late to spook anyone, one imagines - by the Bank of England which reported that at the height of the emerging crisis last year it extended £61.6bn to HBOS and RBS as they were within minutes of closing cash points and normal business operations. In a now rare example of English classic understatement Paul Tucker, deputy governor, told the Treasury select committee "If we hadn't done it, the economic cycle would have been a lot worse".  The rescue has been extremely expensive as evidenced by three separate criteria. The IMF estimates that the total writedowns in different economies on bank holdings at October 2009 were US $1,025bn; UK $604bn, and Eurozone $813bn:- the UK's writedowns being proportionally much higher than any other economy. The "costs" of Government actions, including guarantees, and Central Bank supports were: UK $1,710bn, 74% of GNP; US $10,480bn, 73% of GNP; and Eurozone $1.29bn, 18% of GNPThe third criterion, widely publicised by Martin Wolf, Chief Economics Commentator for the FT, measures the change between the deficit and the surplus in the private sector before the crisis and at the latest estimated position. The change is most easily illustrated by contrasting the German economy before the crisis with the UK and the US and comparing the German economy in 2009 after the crisis with the UK. The German economy has a prodigious surplus external current account balance, approximately 8% of GNP resulting from a surplus of private savings over private investment equal to the sum of a small deficit of Government savings over investment plus a large capital outflow. In contrast the UK and the USA, like most high income countries, had deficits of private savings over private investment and a deficit of higher Government consumption over savings equal to inflows of capital representing about 3% of GNP in the UK and 6% in the US. After the crisis the German position has changed only in degree. However, in stark reversal, the UK and the US (and most high income European countries) have private sector surpluses, just like Germany before and after the crisis, to which are added net capital inflows, as before and the sum of these two variables is matched by huge negative Government balances equivalent to over 10% of GNP. The huge increase in the Government balance is due to a vast increase in private savings, a private sector surplus of saving over investment. The credit crunch has unsurprisingly resulted in a huge adjustment in the private sector.


The UK entered the recession with a deficit of 2.5% of GDP, significantly above the OECD average of about 0.5%. The recessionary effect of reduced taxes together with the fiscal stimulus used to replace the contraction of the private sector has caused the Government deficit to rise sharply. Both the IMF and the EIU report this at 5% in 2008 but rising to between 12% and 14% in 2009 and 13% to 16% in 2010. All developed economies exhibit a similar trend, but, with the exception of Ireland, Spain and the US, to a much lesser extent.    


These Government deficits will cause a substantial increase in the UK Government Debt as a percentage of GDP from 40% (the Sustainable Investment Rule!) in 2007 to an estimated 60% in 200978% in 2010 and 95% in 2014. All other major developed economies have similar projected trends but the rate of deterioration in the UK is considerably greater than in any other economy.


The leaders of the G 20 meeting in Pittsburgh in September 2009 said "it worked" reinforcing the unprecedented monetary and fiscal stimulusCertainly the IMF revised its 2009 world growth estimate from -1.4 to "only" -1.1% and its 2010 forecast from 2.5% to 3.1%, comprising 1.7% from the high income economies and 7.5% for Asia, including 9.2% for China. A return to growth in the developing economies represents a dramatic change from the recent contraction, but at 1.7% it is well below the underlying historic natural growth rate.  Unfortunately even so muted a recovery is dependent on the surge in Government spending to counter, as the IMF says, "the main risk is that private demand in advanced economies remains very weak". Thus, at least in the short term, withdrawal of the current stimuli is undesirable.


In contrast the long-term effects of continuing the stimuli are also undesirable. At present there is a desirable reduction in "yesterday's" private debt but an increasingly undesirable increase in "today's" public debt which could in turn lead to "tomorrow's" financing and currency crises. The rise of 0.33% points recently in the 10yr Gilt yield provides a "to-day" warning of such a "tomorrow" potential crisis as each percentage point change alters the Government's borrowing costs by about £15bn. For the UK to regain stability the economy has to operate without these current fiscal and monetary stimuli and this requires a recovery in either private or foreign demand.  The private sector's financial balance swung from a negative position in 2006 to a surplus of about 10% of GNP in 2009 as shown by a reduction in bank financing and the record reduction of £10bn unsecured debt in the last three months. The current high level of savings in the UK militates against such a private sector recovery and the high savings of the surplus countries' economies, the largest being China, moderate against growth in foreign demand. The IMF includes China within emerging developing economies and shows savings rates rising faster than domestic investment, the difference described as "net lending". As recently as the late 1990s this was negative (ie net borrowing) but has since risen to 5.2% of their GDP. 5.2% of GDP may appear "small" compared, say, with the projected UK fiscal deficit of 13.2% in 2010, but these emerging countries account for 45% of world GDP equal to more than $30,000bn per annum


The conventional economic policy response to a high savings rate is a reduction in interest rates, making saving less attractive and investment returns higher. Unfortunately, however, as interest rates are already nearly zero in many economies, and sometimes negative in real terms, this policy is no longer practicable.


In order to supplement the already fully utilised low interest rate policy, central banks, including the Bank of England, are creating additional money - the delightfully termed "quantitative easing". The success of this policy is a matter for conjecture and  Samuel Brittan, writing in the FT included the sceptical view: "unfortunately instead of being dropped by helicopter, the cash is being injected into the banks that have a thousand and one excuses for not passing it on in loans"


Notwithstanding the difficulties of increasing demand in the world economy, the UK could benefit from gaining a greater share of the existing world demand via higher exports and/or lower imports. Over the last two years there has been about a 20% fall in Sterling trade weighted index which, after an appropriate lag, should be beneficial. Unfortunately so far the response has been disappointing, but interpretation is difficult as there is no control, and world economic conditions are very unusual. The present low levels of Sterling were last reached about thirty years ago. However, the probability of an export led recovery is not high.


The private sector's contribution to a recovery is tightly circumscribed. Borrowing is exceptionally high and deleveraging has barely begun. In 2008 the savings rate was just 1.8% but rose to 3.9% and 5.6% in the first and second quarters of this year, levels still well below the long-term average of 8%. Demand for investment is likely to be poor as considerable excess capacity exists in the economy and many investment opportunities are not realisable because of the cost of credit or of its rationing. The IMF summarises the position "the main risk is that private demand in advanced economies remains very weak". Recovery in the economy is thus dependant on the continuing huge stimulus provided by the authorities. The Economist phrased it "if you take me off life support, I'll kill you". 


This patient may soon be in remission from his systematic debt disease but will be discharged into an environment where re-infection is likely. His underlying disease has a symbiotic relationship with an intermediate host, the financial system, which multiplies, intermediates and transmits the disease so facilitating re-infection. The origin of the disease is remote from the patient, its route to the patient convoluted, and the means of its control uncharted.


The UK economy had expanded since it emerged from the recession of the early 1990s for 64 consecutive quarters until Q2 2008, the largest unbroken expansion period on record. Labour policies, benefiting from the reforms of the previous administration, and from granting operational independence to the Bank of England had in Gordon Brown's now notorious boast "Abolished Boom and Bust"Or so it seemed. The main focus in the "care of public health" of the economy was on inflation control but the risk was elsewhere, as the "credit crunch" so aptly termed, illustrates. Indeed, the Bank was so closely focused on inflation that when the Northern Rock collapsed interest rates were 5.75% and did not drop below 5.00% until October 2008. I wrote in 2007: "The MPC is constrained by its remit to target inflation at a low level on a specific narrow definition. Wider, broader objectives favoured by some commentators and considered more likely by them to provide enhanced economic stability and growth are normally excluded from consideration. CPI inflation, like all "single" targets, money supply, the gold standard, the balance of payments, the £/$ rate and the shadowing of the D-Mark is proving necessary but not sufficient. Perhaps the Bank will surprise us all with a "Nelsonian" turn: "You know Foley, I have only one eye - and I have a right to be blind sometimes ……….. I really do not see the signal".


The emphasis on inflation control in economic management is consistent with acceptance of the macro economic theory termed Real Business Cycle which postulates that economic cycles have four primary fluctuations: random, seasonal, secular (or trend) and business cycle, the fluctuation that inflation targeting is designed to control. Under this theory recessions arise as an efficient response to exogenous changes in the real economic environment and do not represent a failure of the markets to clear or to operate effectively. In effect markets represent the most efficient regulation of the economy and Government policy should concentrate on long-run structural policy changes without undue interventionsThe theory that markets are self-regulating and produce optimal results is a theory that chimes with the deregulation of the financial markets which originated in the suspension of the WWII Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates and the dollar/gold convertibility in 1971, expanded with the liberalisation of the City, as exemplified by "Big Bang" in 1986, and culminated in the abolition in 1995 of the Glass Steagall Act, which had required the separation of merchant/investment banking and commercial banking. UK economic policy is strongly fashioned by such a detached/arms' length approach to the extent of almost using inflation targeting as a panacea:  a golfer with a "one club" approach: "a putter".   Apologists could argue that at the end of the long hole, in this recession a threatened violent deflation, a putter is what is needed, but, before being on the green a variety of clubs is greatly advantageous.


The focus of policy when the storm was gathering was still on inflation and the medicines available were designed for its treatment. The risk from another threat to the health of the economy was almost entirely ignored and no medicines were deployed to attenuate itThe major public health risk was credit, whose potency was formally recognised over 300 years ago: "Credit is a present remedy against poverty &, like the best medicines in Physick works strongly has a poisonous quality": Sir Isaac Newton, then Master of the Royal Mint. The poisonous potential of credit was reinforced by its addictive nature and by the huge profits to its purveyors who become increasingly less licensed. Sir Isaac's views have a very recent endorsement by Professor Rogoff of Harvard who writes in "This Time is Different": "if there is one common theme to the vast range of crises we consider in this book, it is that excessive debt accumulation, whether by government, banks, corporations or consumers poses greater systemic risks than it seems during a boom". The author has studied the data on 66 countries for over 800 years and the main conclusion is that "This Time is NOT Different". Indeed, "cycles of confidence and panic are inevitable in a world of debt……… credit is extended freely and then withdrawn brutally". Interestingly, more recently since 1945, of the 66 countries studied, only four, Austria, Belgium, Portugal and the Netherlands, have escaped a banking crisis. 


Credit is addictive as rising asset prices attract further investment reinforcing the rise and asset prices usually show positive serial correlation in the short term, this for "bubbles", being the length of the growth of the bubble.  Such increases reward ponzi-type borrowers expecting the continuing rise of the asset class, a speculation usually built on a sound rationalisation of the investment decision at the time, later denounced almost invariably by wise after the event commentators, as a "bubble". Unfortunately the existence of bubbles is not always self evident as intrinsic value itself is not. Sir Isaac, Master of the Royal Mint, understood "Tis mere opinion that sets a value upon coined precious metals money…."


Bubbles can be traced back to the 17th Century tulip mania. Notable early successors were the South Sea Bubble, the Victoria US railway stocks, and the 1929 Wall Street Stocks. Recently bubbles have appeared more frequently - gold in 1980, Mexican stocks in 1982 and 1994, Japanese stocks in 1990, Asian economies in 1997 and the dotcom bubble in 2000 culminating in the current bubbles in house prices, initially the US sub prime, and in mortgage backed securities. Behaviourists argue that the evolution and collapse of bubbles has a large psychological component and are linked to the human emotional phases of euphoria and panic: Keynes' "animal spirits". The significant point is that, whereas it is almost inconceivable that the human nature, "animal spirits", have changed over the years, the frequency and type of bubbles appears to have done so.


A hypothesis has been advanced which explains the increased frequency of bubbles, especially those of a financial nature. In 1998 Long-Term Capital Management failed but the Federal Reserve engineered a rescue, a rescue repeated following the Internet bubble and these rescues either altered the downside risk of failure i.e. because rescue was likely or reminded certain participants of the special position they enjoyed in the financial system of being "too big to fail". Their risks were judged to be asymmetric. The weighted probability of the fruits of the upside - profits, expansion and bonuses became less than offset by a much lower weighted downside which excluded failure, collapse, bankruptcy and unemployment - a financier's one-way bet. 


This asymmetry becomes more significant as the financial sector expands and becomes more highly geared. Fifty years ago the assets of the UK banks represented half that of GDP, 15 years ago they represented twice that of GDP and now represent five times that of GDP. In the US the debt of the financial sector rose from 60% of GDP ten years ago to 120% recently, while the UK financial sector reached 250%: a potential bomb getting bigger. There were two further ingredients in this time bomb: the rise of the market economy and light touch regulation which in the UK had been split into three separate components none of which has an overall responsibility. This took place at a time of the significant development of financial innovation and engineering, new techniques that "appeared" to diversify and spread risk often into asset classes believed to have low positive correlations but as it transpired the risks were actually still concentrated and most or all the asset classes became subject to the same adverse factors, all of which required at the very least stronger not lesser control.


Given the extent of the inflation of the bubble, or interconnected bubbles, the scale of resources committed to the assets subject to the bubble, asymmetric analysis of the risk attached to investment made, the inadequate supervision, and the interconnected ties of the so called separate asset classes it is not surprising that we are passing through the worst economic and financial crisis since the Great Depression. The patient, the economy, is being discharged into an environment when the major cause of the disease continues to be harboured by the basically unreformed financial system. Nouriel Roubini comments that "as markets begin to mend and financial institutions return to profitability the drive to reform the regulation of the system is losing political momentum. There is now a serious danger that risky practices and leverage could return. If another systematic crisis were to occur, the backlash against global finance and the free market would be even more severe".


Critics are unanimous on the need for reform, but this is modulated by the need to get credit flowing as quickly as possible to restore economic healthMost critics agree on the need for extensive reform and as Martin Wolf comments acidly, "Doing what banks want is potentially poisonous - fundamental change is essential" - and on the many subjects of reform, including  revised regulation, recapitalisation, lower lending ratios, lower leverage higher capital requirements, especially for "too big to fail" institutions, higher sanctions for losses so reducing moral hazard, and important technical and financial procedure on exchanges to facilitate transparency and objectivity and to provide a rapid resolution regime to assist in minimising the effects on the system of an individual failure. These reassurances are designed to make both the individual "modes" and the "network" safer.


Some proposals for reform are much more radical. These include making the financial sector permanently a heavily regulated ward of the state. John Kay, colourfully describes the banks as being a utility, basic banking including deposit taking and lending to the non-financial economy, attached to a casino whose losses threaten the whole. In such a system the deposits of the retail bank, effectively underwritten by the taxpayer, are used for collateral for the highly-leveraged trading activities of the bank. The takeover of the Bank of Scotland by the Halifax is an unusual exemplification of such an amalgamation - the Halifax was able to gear up its very considerable deposits via the Bank of Scotland's trading activities. John Kay calls for a separation of these two functions to avoid the use of deposit insurance. Further, he adds that the business styles for two such different functions are so different that any organisation combining both becomes unmanageable and, effectively, unmanaged. A conclusion many of us would draw from the current unravelling of the Scottish Banks.


Unfortunately stereotypical narrow banks, the Post Office Savings Bank and the Trustee Savings Bank did not previously compete successfully with commercial banks and would not do so without special protection. In any future crisis deposits would return to the narrow banking sector exacerbating the developing crisis. Narrow banking, being essentially "safe" would restrict the flow of credit to the economy without which it malfunctions just as we currently experience. Thus narrow banking would restrict economic growth unless it was sufficiently "wide" to be commercial.


In the US the Glass Steagall Act enacted in 1933, was designed to restore confidence in the banking system. Amongst its many provisions it curtailed the range of activities in which banks could participate, notably investment business. A broadly similar differentiation existed in the UK until the "big bang" in 1986. Undoubtedly difficulties exist in supervision and definition but it operated, whatever the difficulties, for over 30 years and its repeal in 1999 was, according to President Obama, "more about facilitating mergers than creating an efficient regulatory framework". It seems likely that new regulation will at least place new restrictions on the type and extent of banks' investment and dealing activities, echoing the more rigorous regime existing before "Big Bang".


Reform of the financial system, while eminently desirable, does not of itself cure the malady from which the patient, the economy, is currently suffering, although it does raise its immunity and perhaps reduce the virulence of any subsequent infection. The disease, global imbalances has many foci but, as so often, the principal ones are the East and the Middle East where emerging and developing countries have, in aggregate, became large net capital exporters due to their huge surplus of savings over investment. In some instances these surpluses, linked to undervalued exchange rates, result in reduced domestic living standards, a position only maintainable under certain political regimes. The accumulation of foreign assets by a creditor country certainly reduces its financial risk but beyond a certain level destabilises the debtor nation.


Importantly for the creditor nation the vast holdings of US debt potentially represent more than a financial claim, as they might represent a possible political resource, perhaps of limited value now, but one which in very different circumstances and a very long time hence could be very powerful. When Mao Tse Tung was asked what he thought were the effects of the French Revolution, he replied "It's too early to tell". Shortly after the French Revolution China's share of world GDP was 33% and the US 2%, by 1950 China's share had dropped to 5% and the US' had grown to 27% and by 2014 China's share is forecast to rise to 12% and the US' 23%. Perhaps it really is too early to tell.


To contain the effects of the worst of economic financial crises since the Great Depression required immediate action rather than a more considered approach to its financial causes, the transmission methods and to the presenting symptoms. Fortunately such dramatic and immediate action was undertaken by all fiscal and monetary authorities in the developed economies, including unprecedented qualitative and quantitative measures in the UK, measures which were summarised by Martin Wolf, writing in the FT as "the risks of doing too little are far greater than those of doing too much: sometimes boldness is caution". Fortunately the authorities were "cautious" and the global recovery has now commenced. The EIU forecast that growth in the second half of 2009 will limit overall contraction in 2009 to 1.4% and that by 2011 real growth will have risen to 3.3%, about 1percentage point below the previous five year average. In the third quarter of 2009 most of the world's big economies moved officially out of recession, the UK being a notable exception.


The IMF expects growth to return to levels expected before the crisis, 2% to 2½% for the "rich country" economies, but later falling to around 1¾% for demographic reasons. However the level from which that growth takes place is the lower level to which the economy fell during the crisis. The IMF found that in 88 banking crises between 1970 and 2002 economies do not claw back all the lost ground once the recession ended. On average, seven years after the crisis, output achieved was 10% less than that predicted by the pre-crisis rate. 


Milton Friedman has argued that, as a recession impinges primarily on demand rather than supply, then following a recession the expansion is more forceful because resources, which had been lying idle, are brought back so allowing a period of faster growth. However, in recessions organisations shed labour and mothball or close or scrap equipment and premises. Idle labour and equipment atrophy and become less productive, and, because of the cost or availability of finance, capital equipment is not renewed. This causes the 10% drop in output normally persisting seven years after the crisis. An even worse possibility is that the growth rate is permanently damaged, an outcome more likely with financial crises which erode wealth,  a loss at the trough estimated by Goldman Sachs to be almost equivalent to 75% of world GDP. As a financial crisis develops assets are wiped out leaving the debt secured on them extant. This contrasts with the more typical "inflation led" recession where the flow of spending puts a strain on productive resources forcing prices up which is relatively easily curtailed by raising interest so reducing demand. This process can be reversed and little damage occurs to the capital and labour stock. In a financial crisis the cause is not too much demand but too little, as holders of debt uncovered by assets seek to increase savings to repay the debt. Japan suffered such an asset led or balance sheet recession in the 1990s when a spectacular bubble in both stocks and property burst after which the economy never recovered the growth rate of the 1980s.


Fortunately there are significant differences between these two balance sheet recessions. In the US both the bubble and the burst are much smaller relative to the size of the economy. In both the US and the UK (and elsewhere) the Banks have already been very extensively recapitalised whereas in Japan the major recapitalisation was delayed for seven years until 1999 with a further recapitalisation in 2002, ten years after the crisis broke. The US and the UK recapitalisation may also be insufficient but the restoration of the inter-bank lending rates (Libor in the UK) to "normal" levels in the autumn this year indicated, as Alan Greenspan, a former chairman of the Federal Reserve, said, "things are getting back to normal". In both the US and the UK the authorities have already required the banks to identify and isolate a large proportion of the problematic or "toxic" loans, a model previously used successfully in Sweden's banking recession of the 1990s. This isolation contributed to the regaining of confidence reflected in the "normal" inter-bank rates. Japan delayed such extensive identification of "toxic" assets for ten years until 2002. 


Warren Buffett said "There's never just one cockroach in the kitchen" and I suspect that we have not yet seen the whole family. In particular in the US, where the residential market is so very much worse than in the UK whole mortgages, never diced, spliced and bundled, mostly still lie with the banks where, as the Economist says, "They will bleed slowly". Time may staunch the flow. Asset values seem likely to recover, as already is evident in the UK, rather than deteriorate further and so the wound will heal. Western banks have been much more profitable than Japanese banks and, relieved of the current asset write-downs and benefiting from the current unusually high margins, they should revert to high profitability, so rebuilding their capital bases. Thus as time passes, asset price rises and/or banks' own accumulated profits may assist them in containing any further damage. The Economist compared such a process to a child rolling a hoop - if you keep it turning it won't fall over - and the Western banks can roll it much faster than the Japanese. The structure of the debtors also assists the western banks. In Japan the banks' main loans were to "zombie companies" who could not repay them, but in the US, and to a lesser extent the UK, banks have large holdings of loans to "zombie households". Both types of zombies save remorselessly, draining the economy of demand, but the companies do more lasting damage. Companies use the investors' money to invest in fruitful activities that expand the economy, but households provide that money that companies invest. Thus household saving does not inhibit the growth of productive capacity to the extent that the Japanese company saving did. The West, particularly the US, is not like JapanThe US will not fall into a Japanese-style long-term deflation and by the same token the world economy will not relive the 1930s in spite of such a serious drop in output. 


The recovery will not be prolonged, and the previous growth rate will probably be regained but the gap in the output trend will not be regained. As with Billy Bunter, "a meal missed is a meal lost". The permanent gap in the output trends is estimated by the Treasury at 5% and represents lost factors of production, including particularly, laid-off workers not returning to work, a loss that becomes greater the longer demand remains below potential. The only encouraging aspect of the current recession in the UK is the relatively low increase in unemployment compared with previous recessions and when compared with other western economies that have endured the collapse of the housing bubble in addition to the banking crisis and the ensuing global recession, such as the US, Spain and Ireland. US and Spanish unemployment has more than doubled to 10.2% and 19.0% respectively and Ireland has trebled to 13.0% but in the UK it has risen by less than half to 9.7%. Eurozone job losses have been lower and unemployment has only risen a third, due to the absence there of the property crash and to the existence of Government "Top-Up" schemes for short-term working. In the UK Government schemes with a £5bn budget are reported "to be having an effect". More important has been flexibility within the labour market - pay freezes and short working. Past recessions have not been noted for similar flexibility, probably because the downturn was largely outside the service sector, unlike the present position. The service sector differs from other sectors as the labour cost is a much higher percentage of total costs and service businesses do not have the same economies of scale or operational complexity. Put simply, partners or staff hours in an estate agency can be reduced removing the major costs but a complex manufacturing operation, if only for technical reasons, cannot easily be scaled down and, if it is, continues to have heavy overheads. Moreover such a manufacturing operation is likely to be part of an inter-dependent production chain where any closure has significant collateral effects. In short, a service economy is more flexible, a conclusion supported by the small rise of 30,000 unemployed  only in the third quarter as opposed to 200,000 previously and the current rate being only 8% compared to peaks of 12% and 10.5% in the 1980s and 1990s recessions


The relatively moderate fall in employment will assist the UK's economy to return to growth in 2010, variously forecast as 1.3% Economist Poll of Forecasters, 0.6% EIU, 1% Deloitte and 1% to 1.5% Bank of England and PBR. Forecasts for 2011 vary more greatly from 1.0% EIU or 1.5% Deloitte to the much higher 3.5% to 4.0% of the Bank of England and the PBR, forecasts that seem politically very convenient. Unfortunately, as John Kay points out, the accuracy of Treasury forecasts is not high with each recent five year forecast having been progressively downgraded each following year and the outcome worse than any forecast. He adds that the large structural deficit with which the UK entered the recession is the direct result of the persistently unrealistic projections made since the turn of the century. High growth rates in 2011 are unrealistic.


The Continental European economies of the 1980s are the most likely model for the UK's 2010s with large deficits, heavy public debts and stubborn unemployment: the fear and panic of the last two years will yield to a dull mediocrity. Alfred Marshall the eminent Cambridge economist observed: "The commercial storm leaves its path strewn with ruin; when it is over there is calm, but a dull heavy calm".


Property Prospects 

In the previous property investment cycle the CBRE All Property Yield Index peaked at 7.4% in November 2001 and fell steadily to a trough of 4.8% in May 2007 before rising in this cycle to a peak of 7.8% in February 2009, a yield surpassed only twice since 1970. A higher yield occurred over six quarters in 1974/75, the time of the secondary banking crisis, but when "Bank Rate" averaged about 11% and again in one quarter in 1991, just before Sterling left the ERM in 1992 when "Bank Rate" was again over 10%. In contrast in February 2009 Base Rate was 1.0%. This time last year in one quarter, November 2008 to February 2009, the yield rose from 6.5% to 7.4%, rapid rise equalled only once before in 1974. In the current cycle the fall in value indicated by the yield change is 38.5%. Mercifully since the peak of 7.8% the All Property Yield has fallen in each of the subsequent quarters to 7.5% in AugustFigures published by Jones Lang LaSalle show that in the subsequent four months further falls occurred and prime yields surveyed by them fell from 7.02% to 6.2%, a sudden improvement in the market. 


The 7.8% peak yield in February 2009 was 4.6 percentage points higher than the 10 year Gilt Yield, the highest "yield gap" since records began in 1972, and 1.4 percentage points higher than the previous record in February 1999. From the 1970s until the late 1990s except for one year, the 1993/94 downturn, the position was reversed the "reverse yield gap" and the Gilt yield exceeded the property yield. The "Yield Gap" was re-established in 1997 and has persisted since then until very briefly, only at the recent 2007 property peak


The All Property Rent Index which, apart from a brief fall in 2003, had risen consistently since 1994, fell 0.1% in the Quarter to August 2008 and then fell substantially in each of the following four quarters giving an annual rental loss of 12.2%. The Office sector fell furthest by 19.6% and the Industrial least by 3.5%. Unsurprisingly the largest falls have occurred in the London Office Markets where rents are up to 34% less than one year earlier, followed by Shops outside the South East of England where rents are 15% to 21% less and the 16% fall in Bulky Goods retail parks rentalsOffices outside London are amongst the least affected. Office rents started to fall earlier than 2008 and, since the 2007 peak, All Office rents have fallen 23% and London offices up to 37%. In the last property crash, 1990 to 1992, the Offices sector also suffered the greatest falls, the rental index declined 44% with most of the London office sectors falling by over 50%. Fortunately the fall in rents has already greatly moderated and most forecasts show that after continuing but much smaller falls in rentals, growth will return in 2012. 


Unsurprisingly returns to property investment have been truly awful, just as they were last yearIn the year to 30 September 2008 the IPD All Property Index returned -18.1% and the returns continued to decline culminating in a total monthly return in December 2008 of -5.3%In August 2009 capital values rose for the first time since mid 2007 and have continued to rise subsequently. The 12 months return to 31 October 2009 improved to -14.0% as October witnessed a record, a plus 2.5% capital return. Relative to the other asset classes, equities and bonds, which returned 23.5% and 12.2% to 31 August 2009 respectively, property's minus 14.0% return was even more dire. 


Property's recent performance indicates a welcome reversal in trend. In support of such a trend Cushman and Wakefield report that in November 2009 in the properties sampled by them yields fell another 38 basis points, or 121 basis points since the market low in February 2009, and that prime yields are now 6.2% so reversing 40% of the yield loss since the market peak in mid 2007. Colliers CRE report a "mini" gold rush for property" ….. "resulting in a sharp contraction in initial yields" and suggest London City offices are trading at sub 6% and West End Offices at sub 5%, almost 1% point below earlier levels. The Sunday Times reported "a white hot rally for prime buildings" The FT corroborates these reports suggesting that prime yields have dropped from 6.8% to 5.5%, or over 1 percentage point.


The sudden rise in values is based on investment demand from many separate sources. For overseas investors the current low Sterling exchange provided an additional possible attraction. DTZ report that 81% of the £4.3bn invested in central London in the nine months to September 2009 came from overseas and for the UK as a whole, overseas investors accounted for 45%. These investors include German property funds, US private equity and property companies and a range of sovereign wealth funds, including South Korea's National Pension Service that purchased HSBC's flagship London tower. Property funds are attracting fresh investment as Standard Life for example cite near record inflows of £500m per month. New investment has allowed Aviva to lift its existing redemption restrictions and caused Threadneedle and Hermes to stagger the rate of acceptance of new funds to fit investment opportunities. Last month Legal and General Property, one of the largest fund managers, announced £110m acquisitions, part of a £600m investment programme. Colliers report that some of these funds have 20-25% of their assets as cash and are at risk of becoming "forced buyers". UK Investment companies, REITS and Prop Cos have also returned to the market. Colliers consider that the increased number of willing buyers accounts for the high number of bids and this competition has caused most of the price rises. Investment purchases are being increasingly supported by bank lending. Savills report that compared with six months ago twice as many banks offer significant loans and that other institutions, but excluding US investment banks, are also now willing to lend.  Traditionally prime London property is, as now, the first property sector to recover, but funds are reported as already offering in regional centres. For example two large investments in Glasgow have just been marketed and attracted widespread bids above the asking price and are under offer at less than 6%, one of them Kentigern House for over £70m to Canada Life. The improved investment market is also spreading to "secondary" investments. In November Colliers CRE report that since June 2009, probably the trough in the market, prime yields had dropped by 0.80% but secondary yields had dropped by 1.80% thus reducing the gap between prime and secondary property. Due to the shortage of prime investments, 38% of these surveyed were now considering investments with shorter leases and/or poorer covenant strength. Allsop report that secondary property has sold well at auction. In an October sale realising £83m, yields averaged 6.7%, below the current IPD All Property average of 7.72%, and representing a reduction of the yield gap of about 0.6% points between prime and secondary investments. 


The recent transformation of the investment market has significantly altered forecasts for future returns. In November 2008 the projections for future returns measured by the IPF Index for 2009 and 2010 were -5.3% and 6.2% but by June 2009 this had fallen to -15.1% and 3.4% with the 2009-13 average at 4.5%. Since the market turned in the summer the November 2009 estimates are for -2.6%, 10.0% and 9.4% in 2009 and subsequent years and for an average of 7.4% in 2009-13. The key to the recovery in the November 2009 survey is capital growth due to lower yields as rental values are estimated to continue to contract by 6.1% until stabilising during 2011 and then increasing 7.6% over the next two years.


The change in the investment market is even more starkly seen in the "derivatives" or "swaps" market derived from the IPD All Property Index. The low point for the property derivatives occurred in February 2009 when, after the IPD Index had already returned -23.2% in the year to 31 January 2009, say, net of minus 30% capital and plus 6.8% income, the bid pricing for December 2009 and December 2010 implied returns of minus 22.5% in 2009 and about minus 20.0% in 2010, implying an overall capital fall of about 60%Unsurprisingly those placing any appreciable degree of reliability on such a market, notably advisors and professionals, were severely spooked - a fear that touched us all.


Fortunately that frisson passed as doom was replaced by gloom which may now shade into glee. Six months later in August 2009 the December 2010 contract implied "only" a compound return of minus 3% and the 2009 contract a return of only minus 10%. Since then the substantial rally in the investment market will have been responsible for the very considerable further recent improvement in the derivatives pricing. In early December the 2009 contract - just about to expire - turned positive, a huge change from -22.5%, - and the December 2010 contract implied a compound positive return of 5.25% pa.


In February 2009 there was a major disjuncture between the returns implied by the derivative pricing and the IPF forecasts, the IPF figures proving less unreliable, at least for 2009. At present the prediction derived from the derivative market, and from the IPF survey, together with those of certain surveyors is remarkably similar. All predict positive returns in 2010 of between 6% and 10% followed by slightly lower returns in 2011


"Is this the end of the house price boom?" - so John Kay wrote in the FT as long ago as 12 October 2004. His conclusions were: that housing is good long-term investment, that the current boom will be followed by a sharp slump (as now!) and that those who make "confident" predictions about the future of house prices are mistaken! "Is this the beginning, the middle or the end of a house price recovery?" one might ask today. Last year market conditions and market projections made then were very different from nowLast year I reported that since November 2007 both the Halifax and the Nationwide had reported price falls of nearly 15% and the Halifax an 18% fall from the August 2007 peak. Year-on-year falls of 10.1% had been reported by the Land Registry, 8.2% by FT HPI, and 6.3% by Rightmove, all lower than the two mortgage lenders probably due to delays in reporting and differing mixes of properties. Some new builds were allegedly available at over 20% off "new" prices and bulk new builds were reportedly available at up to 40% off, while repossessions were generally selling for at least 10-30% below already discounted prices. Forecasts made towards the end of last year of the peak to trough fall were very pessimistic. The Treasury and the two main mortgage providers, Halifax and Nationwide predicted a 25% fall, Jones Lang LaSalle 29% and Roger Bootle of Capital Economics 35%. In December 2008 price falls implied by derivatives based on the Halifax Property Index (HPI) were even greaterIn November 2008 the HPI had already fallen 18% from its August 2007 peak and the price derived from that Index was equivalent to a further drop of 21% in 2009 followed by another and final drop of 15%. The peak-to-trough drop indicated was an astonishing 45%. Fortunately, as John Kay saidthose who make "confident" predictions about the future of house prices have indeed been mistaken. 


Acadametrics compile an index of house prices based on complete actual house price data for England and Wales adjusted for season and "mix" of property types. Their figures show that the market peak, £230,000 ± ½%, occurred between August 2007 and April 2008 inclusive. Peak monthly falls of over 1.5% occurred in October, November and December 2008 leading to a market trough of £200,021 in April 2009 representing a 13.04% fall from the peak. The Market has risen every month since May 2009 and in November 2009 significantly was £212,018, 1.4% above November 2008 and only 7.8% down from the 2007/08 peak although this varies considerably amongst regions. Clearly at the present time the market is much better than all the predictions cited


The least accurate prediction was based on the HPI derivatives. In mitigation the market makers did comment that "Instinct suggests that these prices are too low …. liquidity is an issue in this market due to lack of buyers with prices potentially being pushed to artificially low levels …. these longer date contracts appear to offer an excellent opportunity and a large discount" . The FT commented that house price derivatives markets are not the perfect guide to the real thing as they are often illiquid and dominated by mortgage banks seeking to hedge their mortgage exposure. The present derivatives index shows prices broadly unchanged in both 2010 and 2011 but increasing at around 2.5% thereafter, effectively no real change. The Halifax say "overall our view is that house prices will be flat during 2010".


Most commentators predict a fall in prices in 2010 but a recovery thereafter. Deloitte forecasts falls of 10.0% moderating to 5% in 2011 whilst Savills and Jones Lang LaSalle forecast setbacks in 2010 of 7%. The Nationwide predict a "period of moderation" in the months ahead. I see no basis for choosing among the forecasts although the array of derivatives, historical patterns, trends, estimates, statistics and forecasts gives them the comfort of authority but patently undermined by John Kay's assessment of "confident" projections.


The ultimate determinant of prices is the supply of and demand for housing. The supply of houses is relatively inelastic and slow to respond to changes in demand. The supply is limited by the long cycle time of acquiring, planning and then building. The supply is further restrained by the planning process which determines how many houses shall be built in a given place in a given time but then, because of increasing complexities in the planning system, is frequently unable to deliver the programmed number of houses. Within established housing areas supply can be further curtailed by restrictions due to listing, conservation or by the requirements of flood protection. The long-term demand for houses, according to the currently used econometric models, is likely to continue to grow at a rate which is unlikely to be significantly altered, even by a recession as severe as is currently being experienced. Demand also grows with increasing affluence as time, convenience, amenity and quality of location all become of greater value. There is a fundamental imbalance between the supply and demand which will result in higher prices in the long term


The short-term position is subject to other more immediate criteria affecting supply and demand. In the broadest terms there are two sources of short-term supply. Extra supply is provided by current building operations but the industry is operating at a fraction of its normal capacity and appears to have liquidated much of its stock. Thus the supply of new houses is well below average. Existing houses provide the major source of supply to the market in two streams, one elective, the other non-elective. Supply in the elective stream depends on households moving, almost certainly to another house - larger, upmarket, smaller, self-contained flat, retirement home or whatever - and this supply is effectively the same as the demand it creates: the supply is largely recycled. The non-elective supply has three main components: from estates, from household breakups and divorces; and from repossessions and then eviction. The volume of the first two should be relatively fixed, although the recession may have somewhat reduced "breakups", but the supply from evictions will vary considerably with interest rates and with economic activity. In the 1990s recession repossession peaked at 0.40% in 1991, relatively early in the recession, but the present rate is only 0.22%. Mortgage arrears as a percentage of outstanding mortgages are also less than half the 1990s figures. Thus the supply of houses from forced sales, while it may be significant, is likely to be lower than in the previous recession. 


The low repossession rate has two reinforcing causes: low interest rates and relatively low unemployment. Since Repo rate fell rapidly in late 2008 and early 2009 quoted mortgage rates have fallen about 2 percentage points from previous rates reducing mortgage interest costs by about a third. However, an unusual feature of this recession is the very low increase in unemployment in spite of the depth and duration of the recession. In the last recession GDP decreased by about 2% but employment decreased by about 5.5 percentage pointsbut in this recession GDP has decreased by about 5.75% but employment has decreased by less than 2 percentage points. Accordingly it seems likely that in this recession the supply of houses due to repossession will be considerably lower than might otherwise be expected. 


The key factors in determining short term demand are mortgage cost and mortgage availability, effectively a rationing of credit. Due to current interest rates mortgage costs, despite increased margins, are lower than normal, effectively reducing purchasers' costs. Recent mortgage approvals were 56% below the late 2006 peak but were 79% higher than in October 2008 and at their highest level since March 2008. The increase in funding seems likely to continue, especially as Libor rates have returned to levels available in August 2007 and wholesale funding should become more available. Recent measures by the authorities and by the banks have substantially re-established the banks' capital bases and their stability and this is being reflected in the increasing range of mortgage products and the more favourable terms. Even buy-to-let mortgages are increasingly available, a major sign of relaxation. The reduced rationing of finance will increase demand.


Demand is also influenced by sentiment - the housing market is not a "random walk" i.e. where prices are as likely to be down as up. The reverse is the case: if house prices rose last year, there is strong evidence that they will rise this year - prices display positive serial correlation in the short term: house prices have risen because they have risen. This is a strong reinforcing mechanism.


Many contend, presumably for behavioural reasons, that a small rise in prices will increase the supply of houses - effectively shifting the supply curve up so that at any given price a great many more houses are available. For any given demand such an increase in supply would result in lower prices, an outcome the commentators expect. However, the question is not what happens if the supply curve shifts up but why it should shift up! One possible reason for an upward shift in the supply curve could be "sheer fatigue" or "market acceptance", but such a change in attitude should be independent of price changes, and probably more related to the passage of time than to rising prices. Indeed the rational position would be for "fatigue" or "acceptance" to set in as prices fall or stay steady and for rising prices to reinforce the determination to sell at a higher price or at least not to sell at a lower price. In practical terms if you are prepared to sell at say £200,000, regardless of what you think it is "worth" and the price of comparable property is only £180,000 how much do you alter your behaviour when the comparable price is £190,000? Of course you might reduce your expectation from £200,000 to say £190,000 and sell, but such a price is still above £180,000 and the average of all such sale prices is still very near £190,000, much above £180,000. Only if, as a result of the prices rising to £190,000 enough sales occur below the previous price of £180,000 do prices fall as a result of rising!! Thus it seems unlikely that rising prices produce the supply increase more than that required to clear the market at the higher price. Indeed, per contra, the supply might diminish as supply is withdrawn in the expectation of yet higher prices. The argument that increased prices result in reduced prices seems at best equivocal.


The key determinant of the housing market is rationing - demand rationing for the short-term housing market and supply rationing for the long-term housing market. The short-term market will be crucially influenced by interest rates, employment and credit mortgage availability. In my view these will be sufficiently favourable at least to sustain the housing market in 2010. The key determinant of the long-term housing market will continue to be the restrictions of supply by many overlapping and reinforcing controls and conventions, so producing significantly higher real prices.


Future Progress

We are not at present undertaking any development. During the year we succeeded in gaining planning permission for several of our sites which we have added to our existing portfolio of sites ready for development. However we will not commission development until market conditions improve further. We are undertaking minor refurbishments in the basement at 57 North Castle Street, at Carnbo Farmhouse and at Chance Inn Farmhouse. These houses will be marketed in the Spring. 


Refurbishment and restoration will continue at Ardpatrick on West Loch Tarbert, Argyll. Previously we have sold six separate properties, including four refurbished cottages, and at least two more properties will be marketed in 2010. The greater overall development prospects await the outcome of a landscape review required by the Local Plan.


Planning work continues on many of our development sites. This comprises both submissions to the Local Authority for inclusion in future Local Plans and for developments under existing or evolving Local Plans. At Gartshore in East Dunbartonshire, but only seven miles from central Glasgow, discussions continue on the long-term prospects for the restoration of the estate coupled with a high quality "Green Park"At St Margaret's House, which now benefits from a Development Brief, we have submitted an outline proposal for a mixed redevelopment of 225,000ft2. At Baylis Road, Waterloo, there have been a number of proposals, one of which we expect to finalise in 2010.


We have recently gained valuable consents on several of our fifteen rural development sitesMost of these sites were purchased unconditionally, i.e. without planning permissionfor prices not far above their existing use value, and before the 2007 house price peak. The main component of the possible development value lies in the grant of planning permission and its extent and is relatively independent of even large changes in house values. For development or trading properties no change is made to the Company's balance sheet even when improved development values have been obtained. Naturally, however, the balance sheet will reflect such enhanced value when the properties are developed or sold.


I have commented on the investment property market in these statements over the last few years. The broad conclusion was that, over the cycle, real returns were at best poor. Consequently we decided to withdraw from that market and reinvest in specialist development opportunities. In the years immediately before the 2007 crash I reported that investment yields were too low to be sustainable. Fortunately, during that period we declined several very highly-geared investment proposalsWe retained investment properties where we expected them to provide value additional to investment value. 


Our conservative view of the investment market had been reflected in a conservative financing policy and our long-term relationships with our bankers. Our main funding is a low LTV loan maturing in 2011 which, in spite of the significant falls in investment values, has always remained within covenant. Other facilities are with banks with whom we have had borrowings secured over the same properties since 1990 and 1994 respectively I expect these relationships to continue.


The mid market share price on 22 December 2009 was 105p a discount of 37.4% to the NAV of 167.8p. The Board does not recommend a final dividend but will restore dividends when profitability and consideration for other opportunities and obligations permits.


Conclusion

Two years ago I concluded: "The UK economy is expected to experience a major deflationary shock resulting from an unprecedented contraction of credit" and last year I concluded: "Fortunately the recession will pass, but will not leave its passage unmarked". Both these conclusions appear to have been correct although, anomalously, each outcome is likely to be both worse and better than expected. The losses in the financial sector exceeded even the most pessimistic earlier assessments and still seem to be extending. However, proper, unprecedented and timely reactions by the authorities contained the damage: the Economist said "Deft policy saw off disaster". Indeed the recession has passed for almost all economies.


The effects of recession are proving less severe in the short term but will prove more severe in the long term. In spite of the severity of the recessionhouse prices have fallen far less and unemployment and repossessions have risen far less than expected. However, this present alleviation comes at a terrible and continuing long-term cost: huge debts; high servicing costs; lower output and, if remedial action is inappropriate, higher interest rates, and social and political instability.  


History will endow this recession with meaning beyond that currently evident: a watershed in economic management, in political power and moral sway and in changing world order.  


The Group's position has improved considerably since last year and is likely to continue to improve. Investment property prices will rise and residential property prices will at worst be stable. Development sites will increase in value due to planning gains and higher site values



I D Lowe

 

Chairman

23 December 2009

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

For further information please contact:

 

 

 

Caledonian Trust plc

 

Douglas Lowe, Chairman and Chief Executive Officer

Tel: 0131 220 0416

Mike Baynham, Finance Director

Tel: 0131 220 0416



Noble & Company

 

David Ovens

Tel: 0131 225 9677

Rory Boyd

 


  Group income statement for the year ended 30 June 2009

 

2009

 

2008

 

£000

 

£000

 

 

 

 

Gross rental income

650

 

793

Service charge income

24

 

20

Dilapidation income

57

 

29

Property charges 

(265)

 

(234)

 

 

 

 

Net rental and related income

466

 

608

 

 

 

 

Proceeds from sale of trading properties

1,058

 

175

Carrying value of trading properties sold

(661)

 

(70)

Profit from disposal of trading properties

397

 

105

 

 

 

 

Administrative expenses

(880)

 

(840)

 

 

 

 

Other income

254

 

61

Other expenses

(14)

 

(14)

Net other income

240

 

47

 

 

 

 

Net operating profit/(loss) before investment property disposals and valuation movements

223

 

(80)

 

 

 

 

Profit on disposal of investment properties

163

 

-

 

 

 

 

Valuation gains on investment properties

1,932

 

709

Valuation losses on investment properties

(515)

 

(7,870)

Net valuation gains/(losses) on investment properties 

1,417

 

(7,161)

 

 

 

 

Operating profit/(loss)

1,803

 

(7,241)

 

 

 

 

Financial income

7

 

30

Financial expenses

(464)

 

(664)

Net financing costs 

(457)

 

(634)

 

 

 

 

Profit/(loss) before taxation

1,346

 

(7,875)

Income tax credit

-

 

716

 

 

 

 

Profit/(loss) for the financial period attributable to equity holders of the company

1,346

 

(7,159)

 

 

 

 

Earnings/(loss) per share

 

 

 

Basic earnings/(loss) per share (pence)

11.33p

 

(60.25p)

Diluted earnings/(loss) per share (pence)

11.33p

 

(60.25p)


  Consolidated statement of recognised income and expense for the year ended 30 June 2009


 

2009

 

2008

 

£000

 

£000

 

 

 

 

Change in the fair value of equity securities available for sale

(9)

 

(30)

 

 

 

 

Net loss recognised directly in equity

(9)

 

(30)

 

 

 

 

Profit/(loss) for the period 

1,346

 

(7,159)

 

 

 

 

Total recognised income and expense for the period attributable to equity holders of the parent company

1,337

 

(7,189)

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 


  Consolidated balance sheet as at 30 June 2009


 

2009

 

2008

 

£000

 

£000

 

 

 

 

Non current assets

 

 

 

Investment property

17,045

 

16,915

Property, plant and equipment

25

 

22

Investments

2

 

11

Total non-current assets

17,072

 

16,948

 

 

 

 

Current assets

 

 

 

Trading properties

11,032

 

11,383

Trade and other receivables

207

 

434

Cash and cash equivalents

906

 

42

Total current assets

12,145

 

11,859

 

 

 

 

Total assets

29,217

 

28,807

 

 

 

 

Current liabilities

 

 

 

Trade and other payables

(612)

 

(462)

Interest bearing loans and borrowings

(1,985)

 

(987)

 

 

 

 


(2,597)

 

(1,449)

Non current liabilities

 

 

 

Interest bearing loans and borrowings

(6,675)

 

(8,750)

 

 

 

 


(6,675)

 

(8,750)

 

 

 

 

Total liabilities

(9,272)

 

(10,199)

 

 

 

 

Net assets

19,945

 

18,608


 

 

 

Equity

 

 

 

Issued share capital

2,377

 

2,377

Capital redemption reserve

175

 

175

Share premium account

2,745

 

2,745

Retained earnings

14,648

 

13,311

 

 

 

 

Total equity attributable to equity holders of the parent company


19,945

 


18,608

 

 

 

 


The financial statements were approved by the board of directors on 23 December 2009 and signed on its behalf by:


ID Lowe

Director   Consolidated cash flow statement for the year ended 30 June 2009 


 

2009

 

2008

Cash flows from operating activities

£000

 

£000

 

 

 

 

Profit/(loss) for the period

1,346

 

(7,159)

 

 

 

 

Adjustments for : 

 

 

 

(Profit) on sale of investment property

(163)

 

-

(Gains)/losses on fair value adjustment of investment     property

(1,417)

 

7,161

Depreciation

10

 

7

Net finance expense

457

 

642

Income tax credit

-

 

(716)

 

 

 

 

Operating cash flows before movements in working capital

233

 

(65)

 

 

 

 

Decrease/(Increase) in trading properties

351

 

(616)

Decrease in trade and other receivables

252

 

105

Increase/(decrease) in trade and other payables

129

 

(192)

 

 

 

 

Cash generated from operating activities

965

 

(768)

 

 

 

 

Interest paid

(468)

 

(665)

Interest received

7

 

22

 

 

 

 

Cash flows from operating activities

504

 

(1,411)

 

 

 

 

Investing activities

 

 

 

Proceeds from sale of investment property

1,450

 

-

Acquisition of property, plant and equipment

(13)

 

(12)

 

 

 

 

Cash flows from investing activities

1,437

 

(12)

 

 

 

 

Financing activities

(1,077)

 

641

 

 

 

 

Cash flows from financing activities

(1,077)

 

641

 

 

 

 

Net increase/(decrease) in cash and cash equivalents

864

 

(782)

Cash and cash equivalents at beginning of year

42

 

824

 

 

 

 

Cash and cash equivalents at end of year

906

 

42

 

 

 

 


  Notes to the audited results for the year ended 30 June 2009


1.    
The above financial information represents an extract taken from the audited accounts for the year to 30 June 2009, which have been prepared under the basis of International Financial Reporting Standards (IFRSs), and does not constitute statutory accounts within the meaning of section 240 of the Companies Act 1985 (as amended). The statutory accounts for the year ended 30 June 2009 were reported on by the auditors and received an unqualified report and did not contain a statement under section 237 (2) or (3) of the Companies Act 1985 (as amended).
 
 
 
The statutory accounts will be delivered to the Registrar of Companies.
 
 
2.    
All activities of the group are ongoing. The board does not recommend the payment of a final dividend in 2009 (2008: nil).
 
 
3.    
Earnings per ordinary share
 
 
 
The calculation of earnings per ordinary shares is based on the reported profit of £1,346,000 (2008: loss £7,159,000) and on the weighted average number of ordinary shares in issue in the year, as detailed below:
    

 
2009
2008
Weighted average or ordinary shares in issue during year - undiluted
11,882,923
11,882,923
Weighted average of ordinary shares in issue during year - fully diluted
11,882,923
11,882,923
 

4.    
The Annual Report and Accounts will be posted to shareholders on or before 31 December 2009 and further copies will be available, free of charge, for a period of one month following posting to shareholders from the Company's head office, 61 North Castle Street, Edinburgh, EH2 3LJ.
 
 
5.    
The Annual General Meeting of the Company will be held at 61A North Castle Street, Edinburgh EH2 3LJ on Friday 29 January 2010 at 12:30pm.
 
    

 

 

 

 

This information is provided by RNS
The company news service from the London Stock Exchange
 
END
 
 
FR FEFFADSUSEFE
UK 100

Latest directors dealings